The views expressed by contributors are their own and not the view of The Hill

Critically, ‘Rothification’ of 401(k)s not harmful to lower incomes


Tax considerations underlie politicians’ drive to “Rothify” defined-contribution (DC) retirement saving accounts, switching them away from traditional defined-contribution (DC) retirement saving accounts. Rothification brings higher tax revenues today and lower tax revenues decades from now when today’s members of Congress are long into retirement or gone.

Money contributed to traditional accounts is pre-tax money, but subject to tax when withdrawn, whereas money contributed to Roth accounts is after-tax money, not subject to tax when withdrawn.

{mosads}You can see the difference in a simple example: Consider Jane, a 25-year-old contributing $100 pre-tax to a traditional account. Her current income places her in the 30-percent tax bracket. This implies that Jane pays $70 out of her pocket, taking into account the $30 “tax rebate” she receives, yet has the full $100 in her account.

 

That $100 compounds to approximately $1,377 at an annual 6-percent return during the 45 years until she retires at 70. Imagine that Jane’s tax bracket in retirement is also 30 percent. The after-tax amount Jane receives when she withdraws the money is 70 percent of $1,377, approximately $964.

Now consider John, another 25-year-old under the same circumstances, contributing $70 after-tax to a Roth account. The amount compound to approximately $964 at age 70 and is tax-free when withdrawn.

In this case, Jane and John do equally well, contributing the same after-tax amount at age 25 and collecting the same after-tax amount at age 70.

The usual argument in favor of traditional accounts is that marginal tax rates are likely lower at age 70, in retirement, than at age 25, when employed. Yet this is not always true. Low-skill employees might be at a low or zero tax bracket at 25 and remain so in retirement.

High-skill employees might be at low tax brackets at 25, at the beginning of their careers, but at higher tax brackets at age 70, in retirement, when Required Minimum Distribution (RMD) rules compel them to begin withdrawals from possibly fat traditional accounts, and pay taxes on these withdrawals.

Why, then, are so many in the financial services industry objecting so strenuously to Rothification? A cynic might note that members of the industry who charge fees on $100 in traditional accounts when employees are 25, increasing to $1,377 at age 70, collect more fees than when they charge fees on only $70 in a Roth account when employees are 25, increasing to $964 at age 70.

Rothification can disadvantage well-off employees at high tax brackets, such as professionals at the peaks of their careers, who might be at lower tax brackets in retirement. Yet, such employees have both the financial means and self-control necessary for adequate retirement savings.

I do not worry much about their prospects for adequate retirement income. I worry much more about poor employees and employees at the beginning of their careers. They are not likely to be hurt by Rothification.

Moreover, there is evidence that employees are pretty oblivious to tax considerations when they save, whether in traditional accounts or Roth accounts. If so, they might not reduce much the amounts saved from $100 to $70 when Rothified.

Instead they might contribute $80, $90 or perhaps even $100 to a Roth account, increasing their overall retirement savings and prospects for adequate retirement income.

Objection to Rothification is one indicator that current D.C. plans were designed by well-off people for fellow well-off people. Consider the common feature of employer “matching,” where employers contribute a percentage of employee income, such as 3 percent, but only as a match to an equal contribution by an employee.

Matching works well for well-off employees who have the financial means and self-control necessary to contribute even more than the 3 percent necessary for a match. But it does not work well for poor employees who lack the financial means and self-control to do so.

What is more, lack of financial means hampers self-control, as the poor are overwhelmed by many financial demands, from children’s care to utility bills and car repairs. Moreover, many low-income employees lacking the means necessary for a contribution qualifying them for a company match, borrow that amount, possible at high interest rates, nullifying much of the benefit of a company match.

A cynic might say that companies introduced the matching feature to do what it actually does — shortchange poor employees by diminishing company contributions, under the guise of motivating such employees to save.

Consider an analogy to matching in coupons issued by companies, such as Procter & Gamble for Tide detergent. A 50-cent coupon is not likely to entice a person with ample income and scarce time to clip the coupon and carry it to the supermarket.

But it is likely to entice a person with scarce income and ample time. This way, P&G engages in “price discrimination,” selling the same detergent at a higher price to well-off people and a lower price to poor people who would buy a cheaper brand if not for the coupon. P&G would not engage in the coupon practice if all people redeemed them.

Companies offering matching engage in an analogous practice, where well-off people “clip” the employer-match “coupons,” whereas the poor do not. Some employers, perhaps many, would reduce their match if all employees were to clip and redeem employer-match coupons.

Some companies, especially not-for-profit ones such as universities, offer “matchless” contributions. I wish all companies adopted this practice.

While on the topic of employer contributions, it is important to note that the employer switch from Defined Benefit (DB) pension plans to DC retirement saving plans had two effects, one regularly highlighted and one generally overlooked.

The highlighted effect is the shift of risk from employer to employee, such that, for example, employees now bear the risk of stock market crashes. The second effect is a vast reduction in employer contributions to employee retirement savings.

The current average employer contribution in DC plans is approximately 4 percent of salaries. But it was double that percentage, or more, in DB plans. One marker of the decline in the power of employees relative to employers is the current practice of beating up employees for saving too little, while giving a free pass to employers who contribute little.

Meir Statman is the Glenn Klimek professor of finance at Santa Clara University’s Leavey School of Business and the author of, “Finance for Normal People: How Investors and Markets Behave.” 

Tags 401 Finance Individual Retirement Accounts Retirement plans in the United States Taxation in the United States Withholding taxes

Copyright 2024 Nexstar Media Inc. All rights reserved. This material may not be published, broadcast, rewritten, or redistributed..

 

Main Area Top ↴

Testing Homepage Widget

More Finance News

See All

 

Main Area Middle ↴
Main Area Bottom ↴

Most Popular

Load more

Video

See all Video